Results for 'preference measurement'

992 found
Order:
  1.  95
    Stability of risk preference measures: results from a field experiment on French farmers.Arnaud Reynaud & Stéphane Couture - 2012 - Theory and Decision 73 (2):203-221.
    We compare two different elicitation methods for measuring risk attitudes on a sample of French farmers. We consider the lottery tasks initially proposed by Holt and Laury (Econ Rev 92:1644–1655, 2002) and by Eckel and Grossman (Evol Hum Behav 23:281–295, 2002; J Econ Behav Org 68:1–7, 2008). The main empirical result from this within-subject study is that risk preference measures are affected by the type of mechanism used. We first show that this risk preference instability can be related (...)
    Direct download (5 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   5 citations  
  2. Violations of procedure invariance in preference measurement: Cognitive explanations.Marcus Selart, Henry Montgomery, Joakim Romanus & Tommy Gärling - 1994 - European Journal of Cognitive Psychology 6:417-435.
    A violation of procedure invariance in preference measurement is that the predominant or prominent attribute looms larger in choice than in a matching task. In Experiment 1, this so-called prominence effect was demonstrated for choices between pairs of options, choices to accept single options, and preference ratings of single options. That is, in all these response modes the prominent attribute loomed larger than in matching. The results were replicated in Experiment 2, in which subjects chose between or (...)
    Direct download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   9 citations  
  3.  6
    Challenges to both reliability and validity of masculinity-preference measures in menstrual-cycle-effects research.Michael B. Lewis - 2020 - Cognition 197 (C):104201.
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  4.  63
    Measuring the time stability of Prospect Theory preferences.Stefan Zeisberger, Dennis Vrecko & Thomas Langer - 2012 - Theory and Decision 72 (3):359-386.
    Prospect Theory (PT) is widely regarded as the most promising descriptive model for decision making under uncertainty. Various tests have corroborated the validity of the characteristic fourfold pattern of risk attitudes implied by the combination of probability weighting and value transformation. But is it also safe to assume stable PT preferences at the individual level? This is not only an empirical but also a conceptual question. Measuring the stability of preferences in a multi-parameter decision model such as PT is far (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   10 citations  
  5.  7
    Preference aggregation and atoms in measures.Susumu Cato - 2021 - Journal of Mathematical Economics 94:102446.
    This paper examines the aggregation of preferences with a finitely additive measure space of agents. We consider three types of non-dictatorship axioms: non-dictatorship, coalitional non-dictatorship, and atomic non-dictatorship. First, we show that the existence of an atom is a necessary and sufficient condition for the existence of a social welfare function that satisfies weak Pareto, independence of irrelevant alternatives, and coalitional non-dictatorship. Second, we simultaneously impose non-dictatorship and coalitional non-dictatorship, and specify a necessary and sufficient condition for the finitely additive (...)
    Direct download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  6.  21
    Measurements of Rationality: Individual Differences in Information Processing, the Transitivity of Preferences and Decision Strategies.Patrycja Sleboda & Joanna Sokolowska - 2017 - Frontiers in Psychology 8:297604.
    The first goal of this study was to validate the Rational-Experiential Inventory (REI) and the Cognitive Reflection Test (CRT) through checking their relation to the transitivity axiom. The second goal was to test the relation between decision strategies and cognitive style as well as the relation between decision strategies and the transitivity of preferences. The following characteristics of strategies were investigated: requirements for trade-offs, maximization vs. satisficing and option-wise vs. attribute-wise information processing. Respondents were given choices between two multi-attribute options. (...)
    Direct download (5 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  7.  30
    Surveying Ethics: a Measurement Model of Preference for Precepts Implied in Moral Theories (PPIMT).Veljko Dubljević, Sam Cacace & Sarah L. Desmarais - 2022 - Review of Philosophy and Psychology 13 (1):197-214.
    Recent research in empirical moral psychology attempts to understand (rather than place judgment on) the salient normative differences that laypeople have when making moral decisions by using survey methodology that is based on the operationalized principles from moral theories. The PPIMT is the first measure designed to assess respondents’ preference for the precepts implied in the three dominant moral theories: virtue ethics, deontology, and consequentialism. The current study used a latent modeling approach to determine the most theoretically and psychometrically-sound (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   3 citations  
  8.  14
    Measuring men's preferences for involvement in medical care: getting the question right.Melina Gattellari & Jeanette E. Ward - 2005 - Journal of Evaluation in Clinical Practice 11 (3):237-246.
  9.  15
    Measure of Musical Preference, A.Bruce Katz - 2004 - Journal of Consciousness Studies 11 (3-4):3-4.
    Music exists not to be parsed, categorized, or otherwise processed, but because it provides enjoyment. Thus methodologies that concentrate on the cognitive aspects of music alone omit what is essential about this aesthetic form. This paper provides an alternative approach by proposing a measure of musical preference. Specifically, it is argued that a musical passage will be preferred to the extent that it induces synchrony in those brain structures that are responsible for processing the passage. It is first shown (...)
    Direct download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   1 citation  
  10.  18
    Measurement of color preference in goldfish using a negative reinforcement Y-maze avoidance procedure.Dominic J. Zerbolio - 1980 - Bulletin of the Psychonomic Society 15 (2):128-130.
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  11.  37
    Measuring Investors' Socially Responsible Preferences in Mutual Funds.Iván Barreda-Tarrazona, Juan Carlos Matallín-Sáez & Mª Rosario Balaguer-Franch - 2011 - Journal of Business Ethics 103 (2):305-330.
    The aim of this study is to analyze investor behavior towards socially responsible mutual funds. The analysis is based on an experimental study where a sample of individuals takes investment decisions under different parameters of information about the investment alternatives and expected returns. In the experiment, each participant decides how to distribute an investment budget between two funds, returns on which are uncertain and change over time. Two treatments are conducted, each providing a different degree of information on the socially (...)
    Direct download (6 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   5 citations  
  12.  30
    Measurement of preference and utility.Ernst W. Händler - 1984 - Erkenntnis 21 (3):319 - 347.
  13.  59
    Can welfare be measured with a preference-satisfaction index?Willem van der Deijl - 2018 - Journal of Economic Methodology 25 (2):126-142.
    Welfare in economics is generally conceived of in terms of the satisfaction of preferences, but a general, comparable index measure of welfare is generally not taken to be possible. In recent years, in response to the usage of measures of subjective well-being as indices of welfare in economics, a number of economists have started to develop measures of welfare based on preference-satisfaction. In order to evaluate the success of such measures, I formulate criteria of policy-relevance and theoretical success in (...)
    Direct download (8 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   3 citations  
  14.  62
    Parameters of social preference functions: measurement and external validity.Christoph Graf, Rudolf Vetschera & Yingchao Zhang - 2013 - Theory and Decision 74 (3):357-382.
    Most of the existing literature on social preferences either tests whether certain characteristics of the social context influence individual decisions, or tries to estimate parameters of social preference functions describing such behavior at the level of the entire population. In the present paper, we are concerned with measuring parameters of social preference functions at the individual level. We draw upon concepts developed for eliciting other types of utility functions, in particular the literature on decision making under incomplete information. (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  15.  6
    Stability of Risk Preferences During COVID-19: Evidence From Four Measurements.Peilu Zhang & Marco A. Palma - 2022 - Frontiers in Psychology 12.
    This article studies the stability of risk-preference during the COVID-19 pandemic. The results differ between risk-preference measurements and also men and women. We use March 13, 2020, when President Trump declared a national state of emergency as a time anchor to define the pre-pandemic and on-pandemic periods. The pre-pandemic experiment was conducted on February 21, 2020. There are three on-pandemic rounds conducted 10 days, 15 days, and 20 days after the COVID-19 emergency declaration. We include four different risk- (...) measures. Men are more sensitive to the pandemic and become more risk-averse based on the Balloon Analogue Risk Task. Women become more risk-averse in the Social and Experience Seeking domains based on the results from the Domain-Specific Risk-Taking and Sensation Seeking Scales. Both men's and women's risk-preference are stable during COVID-19 based on a Gamble Choice task. The results match our hypotheses which are based on the discussion about whether the psychological construct of risk-preference is general or domain-specific. The differential outcomes between incentivized behavioral and self-reported propensity measures of risk-preference in our experiment show the caveats for studies using a single measure to test risk-preference changes during COVID-19. (shrink)
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  16.  55
    Measuring credibility of compensatory preference statements when trade-offs are interval determined.Carlos A. Bana E. Costa & Philippe Vincke - 1995 - Theory and Decision 39 (2):127-155.
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  17.  35
    A Note on Measuring Preference Structuration.Christian List - manuscript
    The concept of preference structuration not only provides possible escape-routes from socialchoice-theoretic impossibility problems, but also points towards ways of formalizing notions of 'pluralism', 'consensus' and 'issue-dimensionality'. The present note introduces two methods of (operationally) measuring preference structuration, giving attention to both their conceptual characteristics and their computational feasibility. The method to be advocated, called the 'fractionalization' approach, combines well-known social-choice-theoretic criteria of preference structuration (such as single-peakedness or value-restriction) with the frequently used Rae-Taylor (1970) and Laakso-Taagepera (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  18.  20
    Comparison of Objective Measures for Predicting Perceptual Balance and Visual Aesthetic Preference.Ronald Hübner & Martin G. Fillinger - 2016 - Frontiers in Psychology 7.
  19.  17
    Do we agree? Measuring the cohesiveness of preferences.Jorge Alcalde-Unzu & Marc Vorsatz - 2016 - Theory and Decision 80 (2):313-339.
    The closeness of preferences in a preference profile has mainly been measured by aggregating the distances between each pair of preferences. We argue in this paper that some important information is lost in this process and we opt for considering the profile as a whole when constructing such a measure. With this idea in mind, we propose axioms a cohesiveness measure should satisfy and show that these properties fully characterize a new family of measures.
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  20. Retrodiction in quantum mechanics, preferred Lorentz frames, and nonlocal measurements.O. Cohen & B. J. Hiley - 1995 - Foundations of Physics 25 (12):1669-1698.
    We examine, in the context of the Einstein-Podolsky-Rosen-Bohm gedankenexperiment, problems associated with state reduction and with nonlocal influences according to different interpretations of quantum mechanics, when attempts are made to apply these interpretations in the relativistic domain. We begin by considering the significance of retrodiction within four different interpretations of quantum mechanics, and show that three of these interpretations, if applied in a relativistic context, can lead to ambiguities in their description of a process. We consider ways of dealing with (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  21.  53
    The lateral preference inventory for measurement of handedness, footedness, eyedness, and earedness: Norms for young adults.Stanley Coren - 1993 - Bulletin of the Psychonomic Society 31 (1):1-3.
  22.  8
    A comparison of preference and motor-learning measures of handedness.C. E. Buxton - 1937 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 21 (4):464.
  23.  45
    Use of data on planned contributions and stated beliefs in the measurement of social preferences.Anna Conte & M. Vittoria Levati - 2014 - Theory and Decision 76 (2):201-223.
    In a series of one-shot linear public goods game, we ask subjects to report their contributions, their contribution plans for the next period, and their first-order beliefs about their present and future partner. We estimate subjects’ preferences from plan data by a finite mixture approach and compare the results with those obtained from contribution data. Controlling for beliefs, which incorporate the information about the others’ decisions, we are able to show that plans convey accurate information about subjects’ preferences and, consequently, (...)
    Direct download (7 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   2 citations  
  24.  8
    How to Develop Reliable Instruments to Measure the Cultural Evolution of Preferences and Feelings in History?Mauricio de Jesus Dias Martins & Nicolas Baumard - 2022 - Frontiers in Psychology 13.
    While we cannot directly measure the psychological preferences of individuals, and the moral, emotional, and cognitive tendencies of people from the past, we can use cultural artifacts as a window to the zeitgeist of societies in particular historical periods. At present, an increasing number of digitized texts spanning several centuries is available for a computerized analysis. In addition, developments form historical economics have enabled increasingly precise estimations of sociodemographic realities from the past. Crossing these datasets offer a powerful tool to (...)
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  25.  69
    Can one-shot experimental games measure social norms and preferences?Michiru Nagatsu - unknown
    People do not behave strictly so as to maximize monetary payoffs in ex- perimental games such as Public Goods and Ultimatum games. To explain this ‘anomaly’, behavioural economists have proposed so-called social pref- erence models that try to capture other-regarding preferences as additional arguments of players’ util- ity functions. However, none of the proposed model has successfully ex- plained data across different games. I give a proper diagnosis to this situa- tion by examining Woodward’s methodological critique of the social (...) approach. I argue that the problem lies not in external validity as Woodward argues, but internal validity of those experiments. Specifically, I defend the one-shot design as a useful paradigm as long as it is internally valid. (shrink)
    Direct download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  26.  18
    On the use of inconsistency of preferences in psychological measurement.Clyde H. Coombs - 1958 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 55 (1):1.
  27.  26
    The endogenous nature of the measurement of social preferences.John Smith - 2012 - Mind and Society 11 (2):235-256.
    We present evidence against the standard assumptions that social preferences are stable and can be measured in a reliable, nonintrusive manner. We find evidence that measures of social preferences can affect subsequent behavior. Researchers often measure social preferences by posing dictator type allocation decisions. The social value orientation (SVO) is a particular sequence of dictator decisions. We vary the order in which the SVO and a larger stakes dictator game are presented. We also vary the form of the dictator game. (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  28. Social Preference Under Twofold Uncertainty.Philippe Mongin & Marcus Pivato - forthcoming - Economic Theory.
    We investigate the conflict between the ex ante and ex post criteria of social welfare in a new framework of individual and social decisions, which distinguishes between two sources of uncertainty, here interpreted as an objective and a subjective source respectively. This framework makes it possible to endow the individuals and society not only with ex ante and ex post preferences, as is usually done, but also with interim preferences of two kinds, and correspondingly, to introduce interim forms of the (...)
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   7 citations  
  29.  28
    son preference and intimate partner violence victimization in India: examining the role of actual and desired family composition.Shagun Sabarwal, Marie C. Mccormick, S. V. Subramanian & Jay G. Silverman - 2012 - Journal of Biosocial Science 44 (1):43-56.
    SummarySon preference has been considered as a determinant of women's risk of intimate partner violence experience in India, although quantitative evidence from large nationally representative studies testing this relationship is limited. This study examines the association between husband's son preference, sex composition of children and risk of physical and sexual IPV victimization among wives. Information was collected for 26,284 couples in the nationally representative 2005–2006 National Family Health Survey of India. The exposures were husband's son preference measured (...)
    Direct download (6 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  30.  48
    Risk preferences and development revisited.Ferdinand M. Vieider, Peter Martinsson, Pham Khanh Nam & Nghi Truong - 2019 - Theory and Decision 86 (1):1-21.
    We obtain rich measures of the risk preferences of a sample of Vietnamese farmers, and revisit the link between risk preferences and economic well-being. Far from being particularly risk averse, our farmers are on average risk neutral and, thus, more risk tolerant than typical Western subject populations. This generalises recent findings indicating that students in poorer countries are more risk tolerant than students in richer countries to a general population sample. Risk aversion is, furthermore, negatively correlated with income within our (...)
    No categories
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   3 citations  
  31.  30
    Parental preferences for neonatal resuscitation research consent: a pilot study.A. Culbert - 2005 - Journal of Medical Ethics 31 (12):721-726.
    Objective: Obtaining informed consent for resuscitation research, especially in the newborn, is problematic. This study aimed to evaluate parental preferences for hypothetical consent procedures in neonatal resuscitation research.Design: Mail-out survey questionnaire.Setting/participants: Randomly selected parents who had received obstetrical or neonatal care at a tertiary perinatal centre.Main outcome measures: Parental levels of comfort regarding different methods of obtaining consent in hypothetical resuscitation research scenarios.Results: The response rate was 34%. The respondents were a group of highly educated women with a higher family (...)
    Direct download (6 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   2 citations  
  32.  19
    Neuronal Effects of Listening to Entrainment Music Versus Preferred Music in Patients With Chronic Cancer Pain as Measured via EEG and LORETA Imaging.Andrea McGraw Hunt, Jörg Fachner, Rachel Clark-Vetri, Robert B. Raffa, Carrie Rupnow-Kidd, Clemens Maidhof & Cheryl Dileo - 2021 - Frontiers in Psychology 12.
    Previous studies examining EEG and LORETA in patients with chronic pain discovered an overactivation of high theta and low beta power in central regions. MEG studies with healthy subjects correlating evoked nociception ratings and source localization described delta and gamma changes according to two music interventions. Using similar music conditions with chronic pain patients, we examined EEG in response to two different music interventions for pain. To study this process in-depth we conducted a mixed-methods case study approach, based on three (...)
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  33.  19
    Preferences in their Place.J. Lenman - 2000 - Environmental Values 9 (4):431-451.
    In at least some of their forms, Cost-Benefit techniques for the evaluation of environmental projects and policies treat the preferences of citizens as the sole determinants of the value of outcomes. There are two salient ways in which this supposition might be defended. The first is metaethical and appeals to considerations about how we must understand talk of environmental and other values. The second is political and appeals to considerations about democratic legitimacy and the proper aims of public policy. Metaethical (...)
    Direct download (5 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   5 citations  
  34.  66
    Measuring Opportunity.Karin Enflo - 2011 - In Rysiek Sliwinski & Frans Svensson (eds.), Neither/Nor. Uppsala university. pp. 53-68.
    In this essay I discuss a person’s freedom to choose whatever that person may reasonably prefer to choose. This type of freedom of choice may be regarded as a candidate for a social good, being a hybrid between freedom of choice and preference satisfaction utility. To separate this preference dependent freedom of choice from other types, we may call it opportunity. The essay is concerned with the question of how opportunity should be identified and measured. I discuss what (...)
    Direct download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   1 citation  
  35.  56
    The Measurement of Subjective Probability.Edward J. R. Elliott - 2024 - Cambridge University Press.
    Beliefs come in degrees, and we often represent those degrees with numbers. We might say, for example, that we are 90% confident in the truth of some scientific hypothesis, or only 30% confident in the success of some risky endeavour. But what do these numbers mean? What, in other words, is the underlying psychological reality to which the numbers correspond? And what constitutes a meaningful difference between numerically distinct representations of belief? In this Element, we discuss the main approaches to (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  36.  71
    Revealed Preference and Expected Utility.Stephen A. Clark - 2000 - Theory and Decision 49 (2):159-174.
    This essay gives necessary and sufficient conditions for recovering expected utility from choice behavior in several popular models of uncertainty. In particular, these techniques handle a finite state model; a model for which the choice space consists of probability densities and the expected utility representation requires bounded, measurable utility; and a model for which the choice space consists of Borel probability measures and the expected utility representation requires bounded, continuous utility. The key result is the identification of the continuity condition (...)
    Direct download (4 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  37.  8
    Use of Repeated Within-Subject Measures to Assess Infants’ Preference for Similar Others.Amir Cruz-Khalili, Katrina Bettencourt, Carolynn S. Kohn, Matthew P. Normand & Henry D. Schlinger - 2019 - Frontiers in Psychology 10.
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  38.  17
    Effects of kinship, age, and sex on social preferences in rats measured in an operant response situation.Richard Deni, Joseph Vocino & Michael Epstein - 1980 - Bulletin of the Psychonomic Society 16 (1):31-33.
  39. Preference satisfaction and welfare economics.Daniel M. Hausman - 2009 - Economics and Philosophy 25 (1):1-25.
    The tenuous claims of cost-benefit analysis to guide policy so as to promote welfare turn on measuring welfare by preference satisfaction and taking willingness-to-pay to indicate preferences. Yet it is obvious that people's preferences are not always self-interested and that false beliefs may lead people to prefer what is worse for them even when people are self-interested. So welfare is not preference satisfaction, and hence it appears that cost-benefit analysis and welfare economics in general rely on a mistaken (...)
    Direct download (8 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   34 citations  
  40.  33
    The ordinal utility under uncertainty and the measure of risk aversion in terms of preferences.Aldo Montesano - 1985 - Theory and Decision 18 (1):73-85.
  41.  30
    Automatic Preference for White Americans: Eliminating the Familiarity Explanation.Debbie E. McGhee - unknown
    Using the Implicit Association Test, recent experiments have demonstrated a strong and automatic positive evaluation of White Americans and a relatively negative evaluation of African Americans. Interpretations of this finding as revealing pro-White attitudes rest critically on tests of alternative interpretations, the most obvious one being perceivers’ greater familiarity with stimuli representing White Americans. The reported experiment demonstrated that positive attributes were more strongly associated with White than Black Americans even when pictures of equally unfamiliar Black and White individuals were (...)
    Direct download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   11 citations  
  42.  54
    Automatic preference for white americans: Eliminating the familiarity explanation.Anthony Greenwald - manuscript
    Using the Implicit Association Test (IAT), recent experiments have demonstrated a strong and automatic positive evaluation of White Americans and a relatively negative evaluation of African Americans. Interpretations of this finding as revealing pro-White attitudes rest critically on tests of alternative interpretations, the most obvious one being perceivers’ greater familiarity with stimuli representing White Americans. The reported experiment demonstrated that positive attributes were more strongly associated with White than Black Americans even when (a) pictures of equally unfamiliar Black and White (...)
    Direct download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   11 citations  
  43.  19
    The Frog Test: A Tool for Measuring Humor Theories' Validity and Humor Preferences.Ori Amir - 2016 - Frontiers in Human Neuroscience 10.
  44.  34
    Preference Change.Anaïs Cadilhac, Nicholas Asher, Alex Lascarides & Farah Benamara - 2015 - Journal of Logic, Language and Information 24 (3):267-288.
    Most models of rational action assume that all possible states and actions are pre-defined and that preferences change only when beliefs do. But several decision and game problems lack these features, calling for a dynamic model of preferences: preferences can change when unforeseen possibilities come to light or when there is no specifiable or measurable change in belief. We propose a formally precise dynamic model of preferences that extends an existing static model. Our axioms for updating preferences preserve consistency while (...)
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   2 citations  
  45. Measuring Belief and Risk Attitude.Sven Neth - 2019 - Electronic Proceedings in Theoretical Computer Science 297:354–364.
    Ramsey (1926) sketches a proposal for measuring the subjective probabilities of an agent by their observable preferences, assuming that the agent is an expected utility maximizer. I show how to extend the spirit of Ramsey's method to a strictly wider class of agents: risk-weighted expected utility maximizers (Buchak 2013). In particular, I show how we can measure the risk attitudes of an agent by their observable preferences, assuming that the agent is a risk-weighted expected utility maximizer. Further, we can leverage (...)
    Direct download (4 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   3 citations  
  46.  53
    Understanding preferences for disclosure of individual biomarker results among participants in a longitudinal birth cohort.S. E. Wilson, E. R. Baker, A. C. Leonard, M. H. Eckman & B. P. Lanphear - 2010 - Journal of Medical Ethics 36 (12):736-740.
    Background To describe the preferences for disclosure of individual biomarker results among mothers participating in a longitudinal birth cohort. Methods We surveyed 343 mothers that participated in the Health Outcomes and Measures of the Environment Study about their biomarker disclosure preferences. Participants were told that the study was measuring pesticide metabolites in their biological specimens, and that the health effects of these low levels of exposure are unknown. Participants were asked whether they wanted to receive their results and their child's (...)
    Direct download (6 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  47.  44
    Measuring freedom, and its value.Nicolas Cote - 2021 - Dissertation, London School of Economics
    This thesis concerns the measurement of freedom, and its value. Specifically, I am concerned with three overarching questions. First, can we measure the extent of an individual’s freedom? It had better be that we can, otherwise much ordinary and intuitive talk that we would like to vindicate – say, about free persons being freer than slaves – will turn out to be false or meaningless. Second, in what ways is freedom valuable, and how is this value measured? It matters, (...)
    No categories
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  48. fMRI measurements of color in macaque and human.Mark Augath - unknown
    We have used fMRI to measure responses to chromatic and achromatic contrast in retinotopically defined regions of macaque and human visual cortex. We make four observations. Firstly, the relative amplitudes of responses to color and luminance stimuli in macaque area V1 are similar to those previously observed in human fMRI experiments. Secondly, the dorsal and ventral subdivisions of macaque area V4 respond in a similar way to opponent (L j M)-cone chromatic contrast suggesting that they are part of a single (...)
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   2 citations  
  49. Accountants' value preferences and moral reasoning.Mohammad J. Abdolmohammadi & C. Richard Baker - 2006 - Journal of Business Ethics 69 (1):11 - 25.
    This paper examines relationships between accountants’ personal values and their moral reasoning. In particular, we hypothesize that there is an inverse relationship between accountants’ “Conformity” values and principled moral reasoning. This investigation is important because the literature suggests that conformity with rule-based standards may be one reason for professional accountants’ relatively lower scores on measures of moral reasoning (Abdolmohammadi et al. J Bus Ethics 16 (1997) 1717). We administered the Rokeach Values Survey (RVS) (Rokeach: 1973, The Nature of Human Values (...)
    Direct download (4 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   8 citations  
  50. The preferred-basis problem and the quantum mechanics of everything.Jeffrey A. Barrett - 2005 - British Journal for the Philosophy of Science 56 (2):199-220.
    argued that there are two options for what he called a realistic solution to the quantum measurement problem: (1) select a preferred set of observables for which definite values are assumed to exist, or (2) attempt to assign definite values to all observables simultaneously (1810–1). While conventional wisdom has it that the second option is ruled out by the Kochen-Specker theorem, Vink nevertheless advocated it. Making every physical quantity determinate in quantum mechanics carries with it significant conceptual costs, but (...)
    Direct download (10 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   10 citations  
1 — 50 / 992