Results for 'retroactive inhibition, number of interpolated lists'

1000+ found
Order:
  1.  23
    Retroactive inhibition with different patterns of interpolated lists.Judith Goggin - 1968 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 76 (1p1):102.
  2.  26
    Successive interpolation and first-list recall in the A-B, A-C and A-B, D-C paradigms.George E. Weaver & Gary I. Danielson - 1969 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 81 (2):394.
  3.  17
    Retroactive inhibition: the influence of degree of associative value of original and interpolated lists.E. D. Sisson - 1938 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 22 (6):573.
  4.  27
    Studies in retroactive inhibition: VII. Retroactive inhibition as a function of the length and frequency of presentation of the interpolated lists.J. A. McGeoch - 1936 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 19 (6):674.
  5.  13
    Studies in retroactive inhibition: XI. The influence of the relative serial positions of interpolated synonyms in twenty-item lists.J. A. McGeoch & E. D. Sisson - 1938 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 22 (6):547.
  6.  26
    Retroactive inhibition, spontaneous recovery, and type of interpolated learning.Donald J. Lehr, Richard C. Frank & David W. Mattison - 1972 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 92 (2):232.
  7.  11
    Studies in retroactive inhibition: X. The influence of similarity of meaning between lists of paired associates.J. A. McGeoch & G. O. McGeoch - 1937 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 21 (3):320.
  8.  18
    Retroactive inhibition as a function of the degree of original and interpolated learning.George E. Briggs - 1957 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 53 (1):60.
  9.  27
    Retroactive inhibition of verbal associations as a multiple function of temporal point of interpolation and degree of interpolated learning.E. James Archer & Benton J. Underwood - 1951 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 42 (5):283.
  10.  40
    Retroactive interference with multiple interpolated lists.Judith Goggin - 1969 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 80 (3p1):483.
  11.  29
    Retroactive inhibition as a function of degree of interpolated learning.L. E. Thune & B. J. Underwood - 1943 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 32 (3):185.
  12.  8
    Retroactive inhibition: the temporal position of interpolated activity.E. D. Sisson - 1939 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 25 (2):228.
    Direct download (4 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  13.  13
    Retroactive inhibition as a function of the temporal position of the interpolated learning.John M. Newton & Delos D. Wickens - 1956 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 51 (2):149.
  14.  25
    Retroactive inhibition as a function of degree of association of original and interpolated activities.D. C. McClelland & R. M. Heath - 1943 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 33 (5):420.
  15.  6
    Retroactive inhibition as a function of the relative serial positions of the original and interpolated items.Arthur L. Irion - 1946 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 36 (3):262.
  16.  18
    Retroactive inhibition following reinstatement or maintenance of first-list responses by means of free recall.Charles N. Cofer, Naaman F. Faile & David L. Horton - 1971 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 90 (2):197.
  17.  16
    Retroactive inhibition as a function of List 2 study and test intervals.Bonnie Zavortink & Geoffrey Keppel - 1969 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 81 (1):185.
  18.  32
    Retroactive inhibition in free recall as a function of first- and second-list organization.Graeme H. Watts & Richard C. Anderson - 1969 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 81 (3):595.
  19.  17
    Studies in retroactive inhibition. VI. The influence of the relative serial positions of the interpolated synonyms.J. A. McGeoch & G. O. McGeoch - 1936 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 19 (1):1.
  20.  21
    Effect of amount of interpolated learning and length of retention interval upon retroactive inhibition in a serial search task.Robert E. Hicks & Robert K. Young - 1973 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 100 (2):297.
  21.  15
    Studies in retroactive inhibition: VIII. the influence of the relative order of presentation of original and interpolated paired associates.J. A. McGeoch & F. McKinney - 1937 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 20 (1):60.
    Direct download (4 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   1 citation  
  22.  20
    Retroactive inhibition in two paradigms of negative transfer.Isabel M. Birnbaum - 1973 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 100 (1):116.
  23.  16
    Retroactive inhibition as a function of degree of generalization between tasks.E. J. Gibson - 1941 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 28 (2):93.
  24.  32
    Retroactive inhibition of r-s associations in the a-b, b-c, c-b paradigms.Chiu C. Cheung & L. R. Goulet - 1968 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 76 (2p1):321.
  25.  23
    Retroactive inhibition as a function of learning method.Thomas J. Shuell & Geoffrey Keppel - 1967 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 75 (4):457.
  26.  13
    Successive recall of List 1 following List 2 learning with two retroactive inhibition transfer paradigms.Dennis J. Delprato - 1970 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 84 (3):537.
    Direct download (4 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  27.  10
    Retroactive inhibition as a function of preliminary learning.Alan D. Neiberg - 1970 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 83 (3p1):517.
  28.  9
    A study of the affective nature of the interpolated activity as a factor in producing differing relative amounts of retroactive inhibition in recall and in recognition.T. E. McMullin - 1942 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 30 (3):201.
  29.  11
    Intralist cuing following retroactive inhibition of well-learned items.Milton Blake & Ronald Okada - 1973 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 101 (2):386.
  30.  25
    Retroactive inhibition with bilinguals.Robert K. Young & M. Isabelle Navar - 1968 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 77 (1):109.
  31.  17
    Retroactive inhibition in a bilingual A-B, A-B' paradigm.Mike López, Robert E. Hicks & Robert K. Young - 1974 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 103 (1):85.
  32.  32
    General and specific components of retroactive inhibition in the A-B, A-C paradigm.Isabel M. Birnbaum - 1972 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 93 (1):188.
  33.  14
    Relation of experimentally produced interlist intrusions to unlearning and retroactive inhibition.Coleman Paul & Albert Silverstein - 1968 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 76 (3p1):480.
  34.  11
    Stimulus selection and retroactive inhibition.Nina G. Schneider & John P. Houston - 1968 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 77 (1):166.
  35. Epistemic democracy: Generalizing the Condorcet jury theorem.Christian List & Robert E. Goodin - 2001 - Journal of Political Philosophy 9 (3):277–306.
    This paper generalises the classical Condorcet jury theorem from majority voting over two options to plurality voting over multiple options. The paper further discusses the debate between epistemic and procedural democracy and situates its formal results in that debate. The paper finally compares a number of different social choice procedures for many-option choices in terms of their epistemic merits. An appendix explores the implications of some of the present mathematical results for the question of how probable majority cycles (as (...)
    Direct download (8 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   147 citations  
  36. Some remarks on the probability of cycles - Appendix 3 to 'Epistemic democracy: generalizing the Condorcet jury theorem'.Christian List - 2001 - Journal of Political Philosophy 9 (3):277-306.
    This item was published as 'Appendix 3: An Implication of the k-option Condorcet jury mechanism for the probability of cycles' in List and Goodin (2001) http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/705/. Standard results suggest that the probability of cycles should increase as the number of options increases and also as the number of individuals increases. These results are, however, premised on a so-called "impartial culture" assumption: any logically possible preference ordering is assumed to be as likely to be held by an individual as (...)
    Direct download (6 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   51 citations  
  37.  89
    The probability of inconsistencies in complex collective decisions.Christian List - 2005 - Social Choice and Welfare 24 (1):3-32.
    Many groups make decisions over multiple interconnected propositions. The “doctrinal paradox” or “discursive dilemma” shows that propositionwise majority voting can generate inconsistent collective sets of judgments, even when individual sets of judgments are all consistent. I develop a simple model for determining the probability of the paradox, given various assumptions about the probability distribution of individual sets of judgments, including impartial culture and impartial anonymous culture assumptions. I prove several convergence results, identifying when the probability of the paradox converges to (...)
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   29 citations  
  38. On the significance of the absolute Margin.Christian List - 2004 - British Journal for the Philosophy of Science 55 (3):521-544.
    Consider the hypothesis H that a defendant is guilty, and the evidence E that a majority of h out of n independent jurors have voted for H and a minority of k:=n-h against H. How likely is the majority verdict to be correct? By a formula of Condorcet, the probability that H is true given E depends only on each juror's competence and on the absolute margin between the majority and the minority h-k, but neither on the number n, (...)
    Direct download (14 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   26 citations  
  39. On the many as one: A reply to Kornhauser and Sager.Christian List & Philip Pettit - 2005 - Philosophy and Public Affairs 33 (4):377–390.
    In a recent paper on ‘The Many as One’, Lewis A. Kornhauser and Lawrence G. Sager look at an issue that we take to be of great importance in political theory. How far should groups in public life try to speak with one voice, and act with one mind? How far should public groups try to display what Ronald Dworkin calls integrity? We do not expect the many on the market to be integrated in this sense. But should we expect (...)
    Direct download (8 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   25 citations  
  40. Probabilistic Opinion Pooling.Franz Dietrich & Christian List - 2016 - In Alan Hájek & Christopher Hitchcock (eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Probability and Philosophy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
    Suppose several individuals (e.g., experts on a panel) each assign probabilities to some events. How can these individual probability assignments be aggregated into a single collective probability assignment? This article reviews several proposed solutions to this problem. We focus on three salient proposals: linear pooling (the weighted or unweighted linear averaging of probabilities), geometric pooling (the weighted or unweighted geometric averaging of probabilities), and multiplicative pooling (where probabilities are multiplied rather than averaged). We present axiomatic characterisations of each class of (...)
    Direct download (7 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   48 citations  
  41.  35
    A Note on Measuring Preference Structuration.Christian List - manuscript
    The concept of preference structuration not only provides possible escape-routes from socialchoice-theoretic impossibility problems, but also points towards ways of formalizing notions of 'pluralism', 'consensus' and 'issue-dimensionality'. The present note introduces two methods of (operationally) measuring preference structuration, giving attention to both their conceptual characteristics and their computational feasibility. The method to be advocated, called the 'fractionalization' approach, combines well-known social-choice-theoretic criteria of preference structuration (such as single-peakedness or value-restriction) with the frequently used Rae-Taylor (1970) and Laakso-Taagepera (1979) approaches towards (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  42.  11
    Stimulus Parameters Underlying Sound‐Symbolic Mapping of Auditory Pseudowords to Visual Shapes.Simon Lacey, Yaseen Jamal, Sara M. List, K. Sathian & Lynne C. Nygaard - 2020 - Cognitive Science 44 (9):e12883.
    Sound symbolism refers to non‐arbitrary mappings between the sounds of words and their meanings and is often studied by pairing auditory pseudowords such as “maluma” and “takete” with rounded and pointed visual shapes, respectively. However, it is unclear what auditory properties of pseudowords contribute to their perception as rounded or pointed. Here, we compared perceptual ratings of the roundedness/pointedness of large sets of pseudowords and shapes to their acoustic and visual properties using a novel application of representational similarity analysis (RSA). (...)
    No categories
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   2 citations  
  43. A simple proof of Sen's possibility theorem on majority decisions.Christian Elsholtz & Christian List - 2005 - Elemente der Mathematik 60:45-56.
    Condorcet’s voting paradox shows that pairwise majority voting may lead to cyclical majority preferences. In a famous paper, Sen identified a general condition on a profile of individual preference orderings, called triplewise value-restriction, which is sufficient for the avoidance of such cycles. This note aims to make Sen’s result easily accessible. We provide an elementary proof of Sen's possibility theorem and a simple reformulation of Sen’s condition. We discuss how Sen’s condition is logically related to a number of precursors. (...)
    Direct download (5 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   7 citations  
  44. Judgment aggregation by quota rules: Majority voting generalized.Franz Dietrich & Christian List - 2007 - Journal of Theoretical Politics 19 (4):391-424.
    The widely discussed "discursive dilemma" shows that majority voting in a group of individuals on logically connected propositions may produce irrational collective judgments. We generalize majority voting by considering quota rules, which accept each proposition if and only if the number of individuals accepting it exceeds a given threshold, where different thresholds may be used for different propositions. After characterizing quota rules, we prove necessary and sufficient conditions on the required thresholds for various collective rationality requirements. We also consider (...)
    Direct download (5 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   35 citations  
  45.  21
    Retroactive inhibition and the sensitivity of dichotomous indicants.Harry P. Bahrick & Nancy Reynolds - 1966 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 72 (6):812.
  46.  9
    Effects of prior and interpolated learning on retention in pigeons.Jacsue Kehoe - 1963 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 65 (6):537.
  47.  85
    Retroactive inhibition in free recall: Inaccessibility of information available in the memory store.Endel Tulving & Joseph Psotka - 1971 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 87 (1):1.
  48.  38
    Retroactive inhibition of R-S associations.Geoffrey Keppel & Benton J. Underwood - 1962 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 64 (4):400.
  49.  20
    Retroactive inhibition: serial versus random order of presentation of material.E. D. Sisson - 1938 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 23 (3):288.
  50.  16
    Retroactive inhibition of connected discourse as a function of practice level.Norman J. Slamecka - 1960 - Journal of Experimental Psychology 59 (2):104.
1 — 50 / 1000