Pesticides and the Patent Bargain

Journal of Agricultural and Environmental Ethics 28 (1):1-19 (2015)
  Copy   BIBTEX

Abstract

In order to enlarge the pool of knowledge available in the public domain, temporary exclusive rights are granted to innovators who are willing to fully disclose the information needed to reproduce their invention. After the 20-year patent protection period elapses, society should be able to make free use of the publicly available knowledge described in the patent document, which is deemed useful. Resistance to pesticides destroys however the usefulness of information listed in patent documents over time. The invention, here pesticides, will have a decreased effectiveness once it enters the public domain. In some cases pesticides lose most of their efficacy shortly after temporary exclusive rights expire. Society’s share of the patent bargain—having new useful knowledge available in the public domain—is lost. Resistance can be slowed down, if pesticide use is limited by optimal compliance. Stimulating proper use is generally not compatible with existing market incentives for patent holders, since these have to be able to maximize profits in order to recoup research and development costs and satisfy obligations to the company’s stakeholders. Another incentive system is needed to ensure longevity of pesticides, which at the same time does not hamper future research

Links

PhilArchive



    Upload a copy of this work     Papers currently archived: 91,881

External links

Setup an account with your affiliations in order to access resources via your University's proxy server

Through your library

Similar books and articles

Benefit/risk considerations in the use of pesticides.Robert L. Metcalf - 1987 - Agriculture and Human Values 4 (4):15-25.
Amounts of pesticides reaching target pests: Environmental impacts and ethics. [REVIEW]David Pimentel - 1995 - Journal of Agricultural and Environmental Ethics 8 (1):17-29.
Liberalism and intellectual property rights.Hugh Breakey - 2009 - Politics, Philosophy and Economics 8 (3):329-349.
Patents and ethics: Is it possible to be balanced?Jacek Spławiński - 2005 - Science and Engineering Ethics 11 (1):71-74.
Ethics and the patenting of human genes.Annabelle Lever - 2001 - Journal of Philosophy, Science and Law 1:31-46.
Patents.Justine Pila - 2009 - In Cane & Conaghan (ed.), The New Oxford Companion to Law.

Analytics

Added to PP
2014-08-10

Downloads
93 (#184,543)

6 months
11 (#237,895)

Historical graph of downloads
How can I increase my downloads?

Author's Profile

Cristian Timmermann
Universität Augsburg

Citations of this work

Transferring Moral Responsibility for Technological Hazards: The Case of GMOs in Agriculture.Zoë Robaey - 2016 - Journal of Agricultural and Environmental Ethics 29 (5):767-786.
Property Claims on Antibiotic Effectiveness.Cristian Timmermann - 2021 - Public Health Ethics 14 (3):256–267.

Add more citations

References found in this work

One world: the ethics of globalization.Peter Singer - 2002 - New Haven: Yale University Press.
Rights.Leif Wenar - 2008 - Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy.
Intergenerational Justice.Axel Gosseries & Lukas H. Meyer - 2009 - Oxford, Royaume-Uni: Oxford University Press.
Intergenerational Justice.Axel Gosseries - 2003 - In Hugh LaFollette (ed.), The Oxford handbook of practical ethics. New York: Oxford University Press. pp. 459-484.
Introduction - Intergenerational Justice and Its Challenges.Axel Gosseries & Lukas Meyer - 2009 - In Axel Gosseries & Lukas Meyer (eds.), Intergenerational Justice. Oxford University Press.

View all 20 references / Add more references