Discernability and Preference in Interactive Option Searches

The Swedish Ai Society Workshop May 27-28, 2009 Ida, Linköping University (forthcoming)
  Copy   BIBTEX

Abstract

This article has no associated abstract. (fix it)

Links

PhilArchive



    Upload a copy of this work     Papers currently archived: 90,616

External links

  • This entry has no external links. Add one.
Setup an account with your affiliations in order to access resources via your University's proxy server

Through your library

Similar books and articles

Preference for the poor is not an option.Michael Mulcahy & Karon Donnellon - 2000 - The Australasian Catholic Record 77 (4):468.
Why Rational Agents Should Not Be Liberal Maximizers.Isaac Levi - 2008 - Canadian Journal of Philosophy 38 (S1):1-17.
Option ranges.Timothy Chappell - 2001 - Journal of Applied Philosophy 18 (2):107–118.
Interactive kinds.Muhammad Ali Khalidi - 2010 - British Journal for the Philosophy of Science 61 (2):335-360.
Sympathy, commitment, and preference.Daniel M. Hausman - 2005 - Economics and Philosophy 21 (1):33-50.
Pure time preference.Rosemary Lowry & Martin Peterson - 2011 - Pacific Philosophical Quarterly 92 (4):490-508.
Reasons for the preference for symmetry.Rolf Reber - 2002 - Behavioral and Brain Sciences 25 (3):415-416.

Analytics

Added to PP
2014-03-09

Downloads
3 (#1,520,408)

6 months
1 (#1,042,085)

Historical graph of downloads
How can I increase my downloads?

Citations of this work

No citations found.

Add more citations

References found in this work

Physical symbol systems.Allen Newell - 1980 - Cognitive Science 4 (2):135-83.
A Dynamic Systems Approach to the Development of Cognition and Action.David Morris, E. Thelen & L. B. Smith - 1997 - International Studies in the Philosophy of Science 11 (2).
Cybernetics or Control and Communication in the Animal and the Machine.N. Wiener - 1948 - Revue Philosophique de la France Et de l'Etranger 141:578-580.

View all 8 references / Add more references