Results for 'Jeffrey Friedman'

(not author) ( search as author name )
1000+ found
Order:
  1.  20
    Roundtable on Ideational Turns in the Four Subdisciplines of Political Science.Jeffrey Checkel, Jeffrey Friedman, Matthias Matthijs & Rogers Smith - 2016 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 28 (2):171-202.
    ABSTRACTOn September 4, 2015, the Political Epistemology/ideas, Knowledge, and Politics section of the American Political Science Association sponsored a roundtable on ideational turns in the four subdisciplines of political science as part of its annual meetings. Chairing the roundtable was Jeffrey Friedman, Department of Government, University of Texas, Austin. The other participants were Jeffrey Checkel, Department of Political Science, Simon Fraser University; Matthias Matthijs, School of Advanced International Studies, Johns Hopkins University; and Rogers Smith, Department of Political (...)
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  2.  18
    Capitalism and the Jewish Intellectuals.Jeffrey Friedman & Shterna Friedman - 2011 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 23 (1-2):169-194.
    In Capitalism and the Jews, Jerry Z. Muller attempts to resolve Milton Friedman's paradox: Why is it that Jewish intellectuals have been so hostile to capitalism even though capitalism has so greatly benefited the Jews? In one chapter Muller answers, in effect, that Jewish intellectuals have not been anticapitalist. Elsewhere, however, Muller implicitly explains the leftist tendencies of most intellectuals—Jewish and gentile—by unspooling the anticapitalist thread in the main lines of Western thought, culminating in Marx but by no means (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  3.  9
    Capitalism and the Jewish Intellectuals.Jeffrey Friedman & Shterna Friedman - 2011 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 23 (1):169-194.
    In Capitalism and the Jews, Jerry Z. Muller attempts to resolve Milton Friedman's paradox: Why is it that Jewish intellectuals have been so hostile to capitalism even though capitalism has so greatly benefited the Jews? In one chapter Muller answers, in effect, that Jewish intellectuals have not been anticapitalist. Elsewhere, however, Muller implicitly explains the leftist tendencies of most intellectuals—Jewish and gentile—by unspooling the anticapitalist thread in the main lines of Western thought, culminating in Marx but by no means (...)
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  4.  15
    Accounting for political preferences: Cultural theory vs. cultural history.Jeffrey Friedman - 1991 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 5 (3):325-351.
    Liberalism sanctifies the values chosen by the sovereign individual. This tends to rule out criticisms of an individual's “preference” for one value over another by, ironically, establishing a deterministic view of the self that protects the self's desires from scrutiny. Similarly, rational choice approaches to social theory begin with previously determined individual preferences and focus on the means by which they are pursued, concentrating on the results rather than the sources of people's values.A striking new attempt to go behind the (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   6 citations  
  5.  16
    Preface.Jeffrey Friedman - 2008 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 20 (4):415-415.
  6.  18
    Introduction: Greco-Latin Findings.Jeffrey M. Perl, Sara Forsdyke, Colin Davis, Richard Ned Lebow & Yvonne Friedman - 2015 - Common Knowledge 21 (1):10-18.
    In this introduction to part 2 of the Common Knowledge symposium “Peace by Other Means,” the journal's editor reflects on the difference between the contributions to parts 1 and 2. Whereas the first installment concentrated on ethnography, the second focuses on the peacemaking repertoire of the Greco-Latin tradition, whose basis is psychological. That tradition is characterized by its refusal of wishful thinking about human nature and, in particular, by its doubt about claims that human drives other than thumos — the (...)
    No categories
    Direct download (4 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  7.  9
    The Rational Choice Controversy: Economic Models of Politics Reconsidered.Jeffrey Friedman (ed.) - 1996 - Yale University Press.
    _Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory_, a book written by Donald Green and Ian Shapiro and published in 1994, excited much controversy among political scientists and promoted a dialogue among them that was printed in a double issue of the journal Critical Review in 1995. This new book reproduces thirteen essays from the journal written by senior scholars in the field, along with an introduction by the editor of the journal, Jeffrey Friedman, and a rejoinder to the essays by (...)
    Direct download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   18 citations  
  8.  32
    Public ignorance and democratic theory.Jeffrey Friedman - 1998 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 12 (4):397-411.
  9.  33
    Democratic competence in normative and positive theory: Neglected implications of “the nature of belief systems in mass publics”.Jeffrey Friedman - 2006 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 18 (1-3):1-43.
    “The Nature of Belief Systems” sets forth a Hobson's choice between rule by the politically ignorant masses and rule by the ideologically constrained—which is to say, the doctrinaire—elites. On the one hand, lacking comprehensive cognitive structures, such as ideological “belief systems,” with which to understand politics, most people learn distressingly little about it. On the other hand, a spiral of conviction seems to make it difficult for the highly informed few to see any aspects of politics but those that confirm (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   31 citations  
  10. Popper, Weber, and Hayek: The epistemology and politics of ignorance.Jeffrey Friedman - 2005 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 17 (1-2):1-58.
    Karl Popper's methodology highlights our scientific ignorance: hence the need to institutionalize open‐mindedness through controlled experiments that may falsify our fallible theories about the world. In his endorsement of “piecemeal social engineering,” Popper assumes that the social‐democratic state and its citizens are capable of detecting social problems, and of assessing the results of policies aimed at solving them, through a process of experimentation analogous to that of natural science. But we are not only scientifically but politically ignorant: ignorant of the (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   31 citations  
  11.  39
    Taking ignorance seriously: Rejoinder to critics.Jeffrey Friedman - 2006 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 18 (4):467-532.
    In “Popper, Weber, and Hayek,” I claimed that the economic and political world governed by social democracy is too complex to offer hope for rational social‐democratic policy making. I extrapolated this conclusion from the claim, made by Austrian‐school economists in the 1920s and 30s, that central economic planning would face insurmountable “knowledge problems.” Israel Kirzner's Reply indicates the need to keep the Austrians’ cognitivist argument conceptually distinct from more familiar incentives arguments, which can tacitly reintroduce the assumption of omniscience against (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   22 citations  
  12.  29
    Populists as Technocrats.Jeffrey Friedman - 2019 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 31 (3-4):315-376.
    ABSTRACT An intellectually charitable understanding of populism might begin by recognizing that, since populist citizens tend to be politically uninformed and lacking in higher education, populist ideas are likely to be inarticulate reproductions of the tacit assumptions undergirding non-populist or “mainstream” culture rather than stemming from explicit theoretical constructs, such as an apotheosis of the unity or the will of “the people.” What features of our ambient culture, then, could explain the simplistic and combative approach that populists seem to take (...)
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   6 citations  
  13. Causes of the Financial Crisis‗.Jeffrey Friedman - forthcoming - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society.
    The financial crisis was caused by the complex, constantly growing web of regulations designed to constrain and redirect modern capitalism. This complexity made investors, bankers, and perhaps regulators themselves ignorant of regulations previously promulgated across decades and in different “fields” of regulation. These regulations interacted with each other to foster the issuance and securitization of subprime mortgages; their rating as AA or AAA; and their concentration on the balance sheets (and off the balance sheets) of many commercial and investment banks. (...)
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   8 citations  
  14. Political Epistemology.Jeffrey Friedman - 2014 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 26 (1-2):i-xiv.
    ABSTRACTNormative political epistemologists, such as epistemic democrats, study whether political decision makers can, in principle, be expected to know what they need to know if they are to make wise public policy. Empirical political epistemologists study the content and sources of real-world political actors' knowledge and interpretations of knowledge. In recent years, empirical political epistemologists have taken up the study of the ideas of political actors other than voters, such as bureaucrats and politicians. Normative political epistemologists could follow this lead (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   7 citations  
  15.  16
    A “weapon in the hands of the people”: The rhetorical presidency in historical and conceptual context.Jeffrey Friedman - 2007 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 19 (2-3):197-240.
    The Tulis thesis becomes even more powerful when the constitutional revolution he describes is put in its Progressive‐Era context. The public had long demanded social reforms designed to curb or replace laissez‐faire capitalism, which was seen as antithetical to the interests of ordinary working people. But popular demands for social reform went largely unmet until the 1910s. Democratizing political reforms, such as the rhetorical presidency, were designed to facilitate “change” by finally giving the public the power to enact social reforms. (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   12 citations  
  16.  81
    A Crisis of Politics, Not Economics: Complexity, Ignorance, and Policy Failure.Jeffrey Friedman - 2009 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 21 (2-3):127-183.
    ABSTRACT The financial crisis was caused by the complex, constantly growing web of regulations designed to constrain and redirect modern capitalism. This complexity made investors, bankers, and perhaps regulators themselves ignorant of regulations promulgated across decades and in different “fields” of regulation. These regulations interacted with each other to foster the issuance and securitization of subprime mortgages; their rating as AA or AAA; and previously their concentration on the balance sheets (and off the balance sheets) of many commercial and investment (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   10 citations  
  17.  33
    Economic approaches to politics.Jeffrey Friedman - 1995 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 9 (1-2):1-24.
    The debate over Green and Shapiro's Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory sustains their contention that rational choice theory has not produced novel, empirically sustainable findings about politics?if one accepts their definition of empirically sustainable findings. Green and Shapiro show that rational choice research often resembles the empirically vacuous practices in which economists engage under the aegis of instrumentalism. Yet Green and Shapiro's insistence that theoretical constructs should produce accurate predictions may inadvertently lead to instrumentalism. Some of Green and Shapiro's critics (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   11 citations  
  18.  34
    The new consensus: I. The Fukuyama thesis.Jeffrey Friedman - 1989 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 3 (3-4):373-410.
    Fukuyama's argument that we have recently reached ?The End of History?; is defended against writers who fail to appreciate the Hegelian meaning of Fukuyama's ?Endism,?; but is criticized for using simplistic dichotomies that evade the economic and ideological convergence of East and West. Against Fukuyama, the economic critique of socialism, revisionist scholarship on early Soviet economic history, and the history of the libertarian ideas of Rousseau, Kant, Hegel and Marx are deployed to show that history ?ended?; years ago: the creeds (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   11 citations  
  19.  28
    Political Epistemology, Technocracy, and Political Anthropology: Reply to a Symposium on Power Without Knowledge.Jeffrey Friedman - 2020 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 32 (1):242-367.
    A political epistemology that enables us to determine if political actors are likely to know what they need to know must be rooted in an ontology of the actors and of the human objects of their knowledge; that is, a political anthropology. The political anthropology developed in Power Without Knowledge envisions human beings as creatures whose conscious actions are determined by their interpretations of what seem to them to be relevant circumstances; and whose interpretations are, in turn, determined by webs (...)
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   2 citations  
  20.  26
    The new consensus: II. The democratic welfare state.Jeffrey Friedman - 1990 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 4 (4):633-708.
    The goal of the left has been predominantly libertarian: the realization of equal individual freedom. But now, with the demise of leftist hope for radical change that has followed the collapse of ?really existing?; socialism, the world is converging on a compromise between capitalism and the leftist impulse. This compromise is the democratic, interventionist welfare state, which has gained new legitimacy by virtue of combining a ?realistic?; acceptance of the unfortunate need for the market with an attempt to libertarianize capitalism (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   10 citations  
  21.  51
    The Irrelevance of Economic Theory to Understanding Economic Ignorance.Stephen Earl Bennett & Jeffrey Friedman - 2008 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 20 (3):195-258.
    Bryan Caplan’s The Myth of the Rational Voter treats several immensely important and understudied topics—public ignorance of economics, political ideology, and their connection to policy error—from an orthodox economic perspective whose applicability to these topics is overwhelmingly disproven by the available evidence. Moreover, Caplan adds to the traditional and largely irrelevant orthodox economic notion of rational public ignorance the claim that when voters favor counterproductive economic policies, they do so deliberately, i.e., knowingly. This leads him to assume (without any evidence) (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   17 citations  
  22.  27
    The Problem of Epistocratic Identification and the (Possibly) Dysfunctional Division of Epistemic Labor.Jeffrey Friedman - 2017 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 29 (3):293-327.
    ABSTRACTHow can political actors identify which putative expert is truly expert, given that any putative expert may be wrong about a given policy question; given that experts may therefore disagree with one another; and given that other members of the polity, being non-expert, can neither reliably adjudicate inter-expert disagreement nor detect when a consensus of experts is misguided? This would not be an important question if the problems dealt with by politics were usually simple ones, in the sense that the (...)
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   3 citations  
  23.  32
    Motivated Skepticism or Inevitable Conviction? Dogmatism and the Study of Politics.Jeffrey Friedman - 2012 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 24 (2):131-155.
    Taber and Lodge's 2006 paper provides powerful evidence that one's prior beliefs shape one's reception of new evidence in a manner that can best be described as “inadvertently dogmatic.” This is especially true for people who are well informed, which dovetails with findings going back to Converse (1964) showing political beliefs to be ideologically constrained (rigid) among the relatively well informed. What may explain the coincidence of dogmatism and knowledgeability is the very process of learning about politics, which must use (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   5 citations  
  24.  34
    After libertarianism: Rejoinder to Narveson, McCloskey, Flew, and Machan.Jeffrey Friedman - 1992 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 6 (1):113-152.
    Postlibertarianism means abandoning defenses of the intrinsic justice of laissez?faire capitalism, the better to investigate whether the systemic consequences of interfering with capitalism are severe enough to justify laissez?faire. Any sound case for laissez?faire is likely to build on postlibertarian research, for the conviction that laissez?faire is intrinsically just rests upon unsound philosophical assumptions. Conversely, these assumptions, if sound, would make empirical studies of capitalism by libertarian scholars superfluous. Moreover, postmodern approaches to ?libertarianism? perpetuate the same assumptions, in the guise (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   8 citations  
  25.  31
    Postmodernism vs. Postlibertarianism.Jeffrey Friedman - 1991 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 5 (2):145-158.
    “Postmodernism” denotes efforts to replace foundationalist philosophy with contextu‐alist, immanentist forms of reason. “Postlibertarianism” denotes efforts to transcend contemporary minimal statism, questioning both its “libertarian” moral superstructure and its underlying consequentialist claims and seeking to determine whether the latter can be generalized in a way that displaces the former. Efforts to reach minimal‐statist conclusions by postmodern means seem bound to aggravate the problem that plagues contemporary minimal statism: its failure to be true to its consequentialist foundations, reflected in its long‐standing (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   8 citations  
  26.  34
    Freedom has no intrinsic value: Liberalism and voluntarism.Jeffrey Friedman - 2013 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 25 (1):38-85.
    Deontological (as opposed to consequentialist) liberals treat freedom of action as an end in itself, not a means to other ends. Yet logically, when one makes a deliberate choice, one treats freedom of action as if it were not an end in itself, for one uses this freedom as a means to the ends one hopes to achieve through one's action. The tension between deontology and the logic of choice is reflected in the paradoxical nature of the ?right to do (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   4 citations  
  27.  61
    Hayek's Two Epistemologies and the Paradoxes of His Thought.Jeffrey Friedman - 2013 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 25 (3-4):277-304.
    Hayek developed two contradictory epistemologies. The epistemology for which he is famous attributed dispersed knowledge to economic actors and credited the price system for aggregating and communicating this knowledge. The other epistemology attributed to human and non-human organisms alike the error-prone interpretation of stimuli, which could never truly be said to be “knowledge.” Several of the paradoxes of Hayek's economic and political thought that are explored in this symposium can be explained by the triumph of the first epistemology over the (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   4 citations  
  28.  69
    Ignorance as a starting point: From modest epistemology to realistic political theory.Jeffrey Friedman - 2007 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 19 (1):1-22.
  29.  16
    Ignorance as a Starting Point: From Modest Epistemology to Realistic Political Theory.Jeffrey Friedman - 2007 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 19 (1):1-22.
  30.  29
    After democracy, bureaucracy? Rejoinder to Ciepley.Jeffrey Friedman - 2000 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 14 (1):113-137.
    In a certain sense, voluntary communities and market relationships are relatively less coercive than democracy and bureaucracy: they offer more positive freedom. In that respect, they are more like romantic relationships or friendships than are democracies and bureaucracies. This tends to make voluntary communities and markets not only more pleasant forms of interaction, but more effective ones—contrary to Weber's confidence in the superior rationality of bureaucratic control.
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   7 citations  
  31.  53
    “Search” vs. “browse”: A theory of error grounded in radical (not rational) ignorance.Anthony J. Evans & Jeffrey Friedman - 2011 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 23 (1-2):73-104.
    Economists tend to view ignorance as ?rational,? neglecting the possibility that ignorance is unintentional. This oversight is reflected in economists? model of ?information search,? which can be fruitfully contrasted with ?information browsing.? Information searches are designed to discover unknown knowns, whose value is calculable ex ante, such that this value justifies the cost of the search. In this model of human information acquisition, there is no primal or ?radical? ignorance that might prevent people from knowing which information to look for, (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   6 citations  
  32.  23
    Introduction: Public opinion and democracy.Jeffrey Friedman - 1996 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 10 (1):1-12.
  33.  11
    Introduction: Economic Approaches to Politics.Jeffrey Friedman - 2010 - In Louis Putterman (ed.), The Rational Choice Controversy. Yale University Press. pp. 1-24.
    No categories
    Direct download  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   4 citations  
  34.  51
    Roundtable 1: Public ignorance: Rational, irrational, or inevitable?Scott Althaus, Bryan Caplan, Jeffrey Friedman, Ilya Somin & Nassim Nicholas Taleb - 2008 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 20 (4):423-444.
    Direct download (4 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   3 citations  
  35.  21
    Politics or scholarship?Jeffrey Friedman - 1992 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 6 (2-3):429-445.
    Environmental issues imperil the libertarian utopia of a society in which the individual is completely sovereign over his or her private domain. Taken seriously, this aspiration would lead to an environmentalism so extreme that it would preclude human life, since most human activity entails incursions against the sovereign realms of other human beings. The fallback position many libertarians have adopted?free?market environmentalism?retreats from libertarian ideals by permitting some of the physical aggression of pollution to continue. Free?market environmentalism does embody the postlibertarian (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   5 citations  
  36.  10
    Preferences or happiness? Tibor Scitovsky's psychology of human needs.Jeffrey Friedman, Adam McCabe, Joy Rationalism, Freedom Amartya Sen, Juliet Schor, Ronald Inglehart, Taking Commensality Seriously, Albert O. Hirschman & Michael Benedikt - 1996 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 10 (4):471-480.
  37.  63
    Roundtable on Political Epistemology.Scott Althaus, Mark Bevir, Jeffrey Friedman, Hélène Landemore, Rogers Smith & Susan Stokes - 2014 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 26 (1-2):1-32.
    On August 30, 2013, the American Political Science Association sponsored a roundtable on political epistemology as part of its annual meetings. Co-chairing the roundtable were Jeffrey Friedman, Department of Government, University of Texas at Austin; and Hélène Landemore, Department of Political Science, Yale University. The other participants were Scott Althaus, Department of Political Science, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign; Mark Bevir, Department of Political Science, University of California at Berkeley; Rogers Smith, Department of Political Science, University of Pennsylvania; (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   1 citation  
  38.  35
    Hayek's political philosophy and his economics.Jeffrey Friedman - 1997 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 11 (1):1-10.
  39.  27
    Public opinion: Bringing the media back in.Jeffrey Friedman - 2003 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 15 (3-4):239-260.
    Direct download (4 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   4 citations  
  40.  26
    Preferences or happiness? Tibor Scitovsky's psychology of human needs.Jeffrey Friedman & Adam McCabe - 1996 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 10 (4):471-480.
  41.  46
    Roundtable 3: Political ignorance, empirical realities.Samuel DeCanio, Jeffrey Friedman, David R. Mayhew, Michael H. Murakami & Nick Weller - 2008 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 20 (4):463-480.
  42.  32
    Roundtable 2: Ignorance and error.Scott Althaus, John Bullock, Jeffrey Friedman, Arthur Lupia & Paul Quirk - 2008 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 20 (4):445-461.
    Direct download (4 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   2 citations  
  43.  10
    “Search” Vs. “Browse”: A Theory of Error Grounded in Radical (Not Rational) Ignorance.Anthony J. Evans & Jeffrey Friedman - 2011 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 23 (1):73-104.
    Economists tend to view ignorance as “rational,” neglecting the possibility that ignorance is unintentional. This oversight is reflected in economists’ model of “information search,” which can be fruitfully contrasted with “information browsing.” Information searches are designed to discover unknown knowns, whose value is calculable ex ante, such that this value justifies the cost of the search. In this model of human information acquisition, there is no primal or “radical” ignorance that might prevent people from knowing which information to look for, (...)
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   3 citations  
  44.  20
    System effects and the problem of prediction.Jeffrey Friedman - 2012 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 24 (3):291-312.
    Robert Jervis's System Effects (1997) shares a great deal with game theory, complex-systems theory, and systems theory in international relations, yet it transcends them all by taking account of the role of ideas in human behavior. The ideational element inserts unpredictability into Jervis's understanding of system effects. Each member of a ?system? of interrelated actors interprets her situation to require certain actions based on the effects these will cause among other members of the system, but these other actors' responses to (...)
    Direct download (3 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark   2 citations  
  45.  25
    Post-Truth and the Epistemological Crisis.Jeffrey Friedman - 2023 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 35 (1):1-21.
    The polarization and charges of “post-truth” that mark contemporary politics may have its source, ultimately, in a crisis of epistemology, which is characterized by a tension between different forms of naïve realism—the view that reality appears to us directly, unmediated by interpretation. Perhaps too schematically, those on the right tend to be first-person naïve realists in treating economic and social realities as accessible to the ordinary political participant by simple common sense, while those on the left tend to be third-person (...)
    Direct download (2 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  46.  18
    Liberalism and post‐structuralism.Jeffrey Friedman - 1989 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 3 (1):5-6.
  47.  20
    Session VII. A new paradigm for the social sciences? Introductory remarks: Liah Greenfeld moderator: Jonathan Eastwood participants: Ali banuazizi.Carlos Casanova, Jeffrey Friedman, Geoffrey Hill, Natan Press, George Prevelakis, Michael O. Rabin, Nathalie Richard, Joseph E. Steinmetz & Peter Wood - 2004 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 16 (2-3):208-228.
  48.  46
    Roundtable 4: Political dogmatism.Scott Althaus, David Barash, Jeffrey Friedman, George E. Marcus & Charles S. Taber - 2008 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 20 (4):481-498.
    Direct download (4 more)  
     
    Export citation  
     
    Bookmark  
  49.  41
    The bias issue.Jeffrey Friedman - 2005 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 17 (3-4):221-236.
  50.  45
    Methodological vs. normative individualism.Jeffrey Friedman - 1990 - Critical Review: A Journal of Politics and Society 4 (1-2):5-9.
1 — 50 / 1000